THE RETURN OF STATE-OWNED ENTERPRISES AND GHANA’S EMERGING ANTI-STATE MOVEMENT (PART 1)

Photo May 20, 11 56 43

This article is a slightly-revised version of my publication with the same title in the May 19, 21 and 22, 2014, issues of the Daily Graphic. Overall, the article seeks to provide a counterweight to the oft-sung cliche that “government has no business doing business.” It is divided into two parts, Part 2 of which may be found here. This part begins by showing that Ghana is gradually going back for the State-driven development model, where the State actively and directly participate in commerce. It recounts the failure of Ghana’s State-owned enterprises and how that failure appears to supply the evidence that is invariably used to support the claim that State-participation in business is counter productive in all situations. The second part of the article (which I’ll publish later) attempts to dissolve, completely, the force of the cliche. It does this by showing that the State-driven model is the predominant (if not the only) development model that elevates countries from under-development to what has come to be known as “rising economies.” 

******************************************************************************** 

The DIHOC

In July 2011, the then Minister for Defence, Lt. Gen. Joseph Henry Smith, announced that the Ghana Armed Forces (GAF) had acquired the remnant of the then defunct Kumasi Shoe Factory (KSF). The acquisition was done through a 40-60 partnership between the Defence Industries Holding Company Limited (DIHOC) and Knights Ghana Limited (KGL).

DIHOC is a limited liability company held by GAF under its newly-created Defence Industries Department (DID). It is touted as the “driving force and engine” of GAF’s Civil–Military Collaboration for Socio-Economic Development in Ghana (CIMCSED) program. In addition to the Footwear Division, the CIMCSED program currently operates an Ammunition and Explosive Ordnance Devices Manufacturing Division, an Electrical and Electronic Manufacturing Division, a Shipbuilding Manufacturing Division, a Textile and Garment Manufacturing Division and a Solar Manufacturing Division. It also operates a Printing and Publishing Division, a Construction and Civil Work Division, an Agriculture & Agro-processing Division and a Pharmaceuticals Manufacturing Division.  What is worth noting here is that DIHOC is a State-owned enterprise (SOE).

KGL on the other hand is a privately-held Ghanaian company with a Czech heritage. 

In 2009, the DIHOC-KGL partnership submitted a bid to the Divestiture Implementation Committee (DIC) for the acquisition of the defunct shoe factory. The bid was accepted and work on reviving the factory which collapsed in the 1970s commenced later that year.

Opposition

The CIMCSED program in general and the DIHOC-KGL acquisition in particular, however, faced pockets of opposition from certain interests. The opposition was founded upon a number of reasons. Some raised questions over the mandate of GAF. They queried how the military, a State institution whose core mandate is to use bombs, guns, knives, and military intelligence to defend the territorial integrity of Ghana, could be engaged in such commercial activities.

Others went as far as questioning the entrepreneurial acumen of the officers and men of GAF, and even the very capacity of Knight A.S. (the Czech holder of KGL) to manufacture shoes. Some, too, relied on the sad history of Ghana’s State-owned enterprises (SOEs) and questioned the viability of not just the DIHOC venture, but also SOEs in general.

Yet still, the ideologically-persuaded were not slow at using the opportunity to launch a full-scale ideological warfare. They trumpeted a very familiar cliché, namely, that “government has no business doing business.” In fact, by October 2012, some high-ranking social commentators had started claiming credit for predicting in 2011 that the project would not see the light of day.

For the purposes of simplicity, I will invariably refer to this group of interests as the Ghana anti-State movement, not least because they seem extremely antagonistic to any idea of State commerce.

DIHOC Shoes

Last week, about 4 years after the DIHOC-KGL partnership was given the green light by the DIC, the President, H.E. John Mahama, went to Kumasi to launch the revival of the factory. The factory currently has about 400 women and men in its employment and is capable of producing 1.8 million pairs of shoes a year.

At the luncheon, the President announced that the government will purchase DIHOC shoes for distribution to school children under the free school uniform program. GAF has announced its intention to order 16, 000 pairs of boots for its women, men and officers from the factory, while the Ghana Immigration Service has already taken delivery of some 4,000 boots. This is quite apart from what other private individuals and institutions have and will continue to purchase. The factory aims at feeding the African shoe market by the  year 2018.

This seems to have stung the Ghana anti-State movement very badly, causing them to resume the recitation of the anti-State cliché – ‘government has no business doing business.’

The New National Development Model

The DIHOC shoe story aside. Government has been incorporating new SOEs recently. An example is the Ghana Gas Company Limited, which was incorporated in 2011. Just two weeks ago the chairman of the National Development Planning Commission (NDPC), Mr. P.V. Obeng, announced to a group of workers in the industrial city of Tema that a new development model will be launched later this year. The B&FT reports him to have mentioned that the new model will chart a “new economic path where the role of the State would be paramount.”

Taken together, there is no doubt that the governments activities are going to keep the Ghana anti-State movement very busy for the next godknows how many decades.

‘Government has no Business doing Business’

The cliché ‘government has no business doing business’ may mean so many things. But its core tenet is that government, the State, should take its hands off business. The State should not be seen to be investing national resources into commercial enterprises. This supposition is based on the idea that the State is very terrible at running business while private hands are better (than the State) at driving development. The corollary of supposition is that commercial enterprises should be reserved for private hands, while the State creates what is often referred to as ‘conducive environment.’ In sum, subscribers to the cliché decry any idea of State-owned enterprise outrightly.

A necessary offshoot of the cliché is that the failure or success of an enterprise is largely dependent on whether it is owned by a private hand or by the State. In this regard, it is important to mention that this cliché makes no exception to the nature of the political economy within which the enterprise operates.

However, is there enough merit in this claim? Put slightly differently, is it really true that ownership per se explains the success or failure of companies, so that by merely offloading the shares of a State-owned company into private hands, that company would transmogrify into a high performing enterprise?

I wish to make a case in support of the claim that there is more to a company’s performance than the question of who owns its shares or controls it. More specifically, I argue that companies do not succeed simply because they are owned or controlled by private persons; neither do they fail simply because they are owned and operated by the State.

If this argument is true, then, we should see enterprises failing or succeeding irrespective of whether they are owned or controlled by a State or a private person. However if it is false, that is, if the Ghana anti-State movement is right, then we should not see SOEs succeeding on a large scale or privately-owned enterprises failing on a large scale in any political economy.

May I add that this topic has long been flogged extensively elsewhere. It would not have required much discussion here, but for the recent overreliance on this cliché by the Ghana anti-State movement. I will therefore focus much of the discussion on drawing attention to what seems to have eluded the movement, namely, how State involvement elsewhere has helped to lift economies out of underdevelopment. I will show that hardly, if at all, do underdeveloped or developing economies become global players by excluding the State from directly engaging in business.

The Rise of Ghana’s SOEs

We may need to do a little history by way of creating a context for the discussion. Without it we will not know where we come from and, consequently, where we are heading.

Colonization deprives a colonized people of skilled labour, modern technology, access to capital, direct access to the global market, self-confidence and clout. These denials result in a weak (if not non-existent) competitive indigenous private sector. This was the case in Ghana at independence.

John Esseks, thus, gives the following account of the structure of Ghana’s economy:

“In March 1957, when Ghana gained her political independence, over 90 percent of the country’s import trade was in the hands of foreign firms; two British banks shared about 90 percent of all banking business; expatriate companies held 96 percent of total timber concessions; foreign investors owned all functioning gold mines and controlled about half of the annual diamond production; general insurance was entirely in the hands of expatriate firms; and foreign companies earned the bulk of total receipts in the small manufacturing sector.”

The overarching aim of the fight for independence was to take control over our own affairs. However, becoming a global players in our own right was also an integral part of the struggle. Attaining this goal required us to catch up with the global players, who were at the time a couple of centuries ahead. Catching up required a well-coordinated and a more aggressive development plan. We needed to run while others walk.

How do we do this with the very weak, largely-disorganised and heavily-unskilled private sector that colonialism left us with? State-ownership and control of the factors of production, it appeared, was the only plausible way by which the former colonies, including Ghana, could launch themselves onto the much developed and far more sophisticated global market.

Therefore, Ghana, like most former colonies, began its statehood with an economy which rested almost-entirely on SOEs. Through the de-colonization process, the State became a major player in almost all the sectors of the economy – transportation, aviation, agriculture, fishing, education, manufacturing, commerce and even entertainment. Barely 5 years after Ghana attained a republican status, John Esseks reports, again, in another publication:

“By 1965 the state importing enterprise handled 35 percent of the country’s total commercial imports; the state insurance corporation transacted about 50 percent of all insurance business; the government’s commercial bank accounted for over 60 percent of total deposits; the state-owned Black Star Line carried about 17 percent of Ghana’s seabourne commerce; the government’s Ghana National Construction Corporation had succeeded in displacing almost all private contractors from the largest subsector of building and construction, that financed by public funds; and the factories owned by the state or partnerships between government and private interests produced 27 percent of total output in manufacturing.

We were on track. But those were the glorious days of SEOs in Ghana. They were short-lived.

The fall of Ghana’s SEOs

One great evil that afflicts SOEs is political influence; I mean misguided political influence. The evil becomes even greater when the polity within which the SOEs operate lacks stability; and even much worse when competent, skilled and public-spirited management and strong capital market institutions are lacking. Ghana bore all these elements in significant proportions after the middle of the 1960s. Thus, by the close of the 1970s, most of the public corporations had been ran down.

The country was heavily engrossed in debt owed to the countries and institutions of the industrialised West. Inflation rate was swinging above 100%; GDP per capita had fallen from US$ 1,007 in 1960 to barely US$ 700 in 1983; and unemployment hitting all time high. Countrymen were compelled by the severe economic conditions to embark on a desperate search for greener pastures outside the country’s borders. Ghana has abdicated the throne of grace and has settled for the mat of withered grass.

The Case of the Ghana anti-State Movement

At this point, one could hardly dismiss the concerns of the Ghana anti-State movement. These facts supplied all the evidence that one needs to support the claims that State-ownership or control of companies is a waste of public money and everyone’s time. With these facts, one could hardly dispute the claim that State-ownership is a prime promoter monopoly, rent-seeking, corruption, cronyism, nepotism, political interference, etc.

Indeed, all this formed a major part of the operating causes of the failure of SOEs in former colonies in general and Ghana in particular. These observations, thus, inform and are at the heart of the wholesale condemnation of everything State.

Further, this vivid body of evidence also readily fed into the neoliberal rhetoric on whose back the western side of the Cold War rode to glory. It also formed the basis of the World Bank’s privatization programs that swept across Africa, Europe and Latin America starting from the 1970s. It is recorded that the World Bank, between 1988 and 1993, saw some 2,655 SOEs privatised in the world, valuing over US$ 270 billion.

****************************************************************************

I will pause here. In Part 2 of the article, I will show that the State-driven approach to development has recorded tremendous achievements elsewhere; and has, contrary to the cliche, transformed underdeveloped economies into players on the global stage. It will begin with a brief descriptive of the the World Bank/IMF divestiture program and how Ghana’s economy is yet to benefit from it. The Part will, then, end with several questions which are meant to signal a reassessment by the Ghana anti-State movement of their position.

One thought on “THE RETURN OF STATE-OWNED ENTERPRISES AND GHANA’S EMERGING ANTI-STATE MOVEMENT (PART 1)

  1. Pingback: THE RETURN OF STATE-OWNED ENTERPRISES AND GHANA’S EMERGING ANTI-STATE MOVEMENT (PART 2) | theoyibo

Leave a Reply

Fill in your details below or click an icon to log in:

WordPress.com Logo

You are commenting using your WordPress.com account. Log Out /  Change )

Google+ photo

You are commenting using your Google+ account. Log Out /  Change )

Twitter picture

You are commenting using your Twitter account. Log Out /  Change )

Facebook photo

You are commenting using your Facebook account. Log Out /  Change )

Connecting to %s